Loading

Towards An International Model Of Portable Migrant Social Protection Scheme

Abstract

Most countries exclude foreign migrant workers from their national pension schemes. Migrants who get end-of-service gratuities in lieu of deferred pension benefits often lack the financial skills and access to institutions that offer efficiently diversified, low-cost pension products. Existing defined contribution pension schemes are not internationally portable and face unfavorable tax treatments.

We propose that the G20 and the relevant international organizations develop model documents and agreements to support the development of internationally portable pension-investment accounts for migrant workers. The models would facilitate the development of robust internationally portable pension schemes and support inclusive growth by expanding ownership of equities to migrant workers.

 

Challenge

Millions of international migrant workers lack old-age financial protection. [1] Only a small share of migrant workers are included in their host or home country pension schemes. Some migrants may get end-of-service gratuities in lieu of deferred pension benefits. However, poorer or lower educated migrants are unlikely to have the knowledge, skills—including numeracy skills—incentives, and/or access to institutions where they can invest efficiently and earn the equity premium to support themselves in retirement (Cole and Shastry, 2009; Khorunzhina, 2013; Lusardi, 2012; Lusardi, et al., 2013). Many low-cost asset managers are unlikely to offer accounts to migrants due to the reporting and compliance burden related to overlapping tax and legal jurisdictions of such clients.

Migrants who are part of their host country’s pension schemes face another challenge: the lack of international portability of pension accounts and unfavorable tax treatment after they move to another country. Migrant workers participating in their host country’s public or private pension schemes often have no choice but to withdraw their contributions upon departure from the country. They forego some of the accrued benefits earned with tenure and may have to pay a tax on the lump-sum withdrawal in the host, and possibly the home country.

The International Labor Organization (ILO 2013; Hirose, Nikacˇ, and Tamagno, 2011), International Social Security Association (ISSA, 2014), and several researchers (Genser and Holzmann, 2016; Holzmann, 2013; Holzmann, et al., 2016; Migrant Forum in Asia, 2013; Sabates-Wheeler and Koettl, 2010) studied the coverage and policies to improve social protection of migrant workers. All highlight severe disadvantages in accessing social protection for old-age retirement. Since 1925, ILO has developed several specific standards for the protection of migrant workers’ social security rights (ILO, 2013 page 3)[2]. The Maintenance of Migrants’ Pension Rights Convention, 1935 (No. 48) was the most focused attempt to provide migrant workers with access to host countries’ old-age social protection schemes. However, only 12 countries ratified the convention, and it has been shelved.

ILO’s preferred solution seemed to have been to include migrant workers in domestic social protection systems. The inclusion would have ensured equitable treatment across all workers and reduce labor market distortions. However, many countries have been unwilling to include migrant workers in their pay-as-you-go (PAYG) or even capitalized, defined contribution schemes. Most migrant workers are poor and migrate to affluent countries where social assistance is quite generous and redistributive towards citizens with lower incomes. Therefore, policymakers have resisted including foreign workers in redistributive schemes, in particular when they expected them to retire outside the host country. Moreover, politically disenfranchised migrant workers cannot or do not vote. Some supporters may see a universal (basic) income, launched globally, as a viable universal social protection scheme (Grimalda, et al., 2021). However, early experiences with universal income experiments have not been promising (Verho, et al., 2022). At the same time, many advanced countries have been trying for decades to reduce PAYG-related pension liabilities to restore the long-term sustainability of the schemes undermined by an aging population.

 

Proposal

Governments routinely pursue policies to increase self-reliance and individual saving among the population. While sound socio-economic policies accept the need for social solidarity (Euzéby, 1997), successful social welfare policies distinguish between routine life-cycle demands and unpredictable events. They encourage people to prepare for routine events by saving and insuring, while the government, as the insurer of the last resort, builds financial and other buffers, and stands ready to help deal with major natural disasters, economic or financial crises, and Black Swan events. Successful policies minimize moral hazard and the related reliance on taxpayer or charity assistance. Policies range from encouraging individuals to explore increasing savings, incentivizing them to save more, helping and nudging them to improve the quality of investment decisions, make the “right” choices, and mandating or prohibiting choices (Annex 1).

We propose a pragmatic approach to supporting migrant workers’ right to social insurance, including old-age, disability, and survivors’ pension. [3] We recommend that policymakers promote efficient, internationally portable defined contribution plans. Defined contribution plans are likely to gain political support across the world because they do not involve redistribution of benefits from citizens to foreigners. Moreover, they align with already-in-progress reforms in many national pension systems that try to restore their long-term sustainability and reduce the distortions brought by generous PAYG schemes (Barr, 2012, 2013; Ehrlich and Kim, 2005; Redonda, et al., 2019). [4] Defined contribution schemes avoid the negatives of the PAYG system and offer tangible benefits for migrant workers as well as their host and home countries. We note that migrant workers could view their mandatory inclusion in traditional PAYG schemes in host countries as a cynical attempt to make them support retirees in their host countries in exchange for an economically unrealistic promise of future benefits.

Host countries should encourage their foreign workers to save and help them deploy their savings efficiently. Historically, people who invested savings in equities earned a higher rate of return than those who kept savings in ultra-safe bank deposits or government bonds (Barro and Misra, 2013, Table 1). By diversifying internationally, savers can reduce wealth and income volatility and vulnerabilities to shocks. High participation in efficient, well diversified savings-investment schemes reduces inequality, promotes growth by minimizing tax-induced distortions and disincentives to work, improves fiscal sustainability, and undermines support for destabilizing political “populism”, in particular, in the world of the growing share of returns to capital in GDP. In addition, by ensuring that today’s migrants save for retirement, host countries buy valuable financial insurance in the event the workers settle in their host country, as is likely to happen even more often in the future.

We call on G20 policymakers to support the development of self-funded, internationally portable, social protection schemes. The schemes, in addition to old-age protection, could offer unemployment insurance and support routine life-cycle expenditure, including health care and education, to facilitate continuous productivity growth and successful participation in the labor market (Hartley, et al., 2010; Schulz, 2002; Vogel, et al., 2013).

We propose G20 members and the leading low-cost financial intermediaries design the following uniform schemes for international voluntary adoption: 

  1. A Model of “Internationally Portable Pension Scheme” (IPPS).
  2. A Model of “International Migrant Pension Investment Account” (IMPIA).
  3. A Model of “Tax Treatment and Treaty” to provide a uniform tax treatment of savings and investments in IMPIAs and facilitate their full international portability.

The G20 is uniquely placed to coordinate the development of the model documents and institutional arrangements to support internationally portable migrant savings schemes, investment accounts, and their uniform, non-discriminatory tax treatment across tax jurisdictions. The Development and Employment Working Groups (under the Sherpa Track) in collaboration with the Finance Track, in particular, its Global Partnership for Financial Inclusion, could draft a roadmap for the development of the Model documents and their implementation starting in 2023, under India’s presidency of the G20. [5] 

G20 members and relevant financial intermediaries would encourage countries to adopt the Model documents and institutional solutions—voluntarily—and offer their benefits to migrant workers. The Model documents would give the highest legal private property protections possible and require the signatories to guarantee full transferability of funds to beneficiaries designated by the account owner upon the owner’s death (Fultz, 2012; Kay, 2009).

T20 has routinely called for measures to improve the fate of migrants. Stein-Zalai and Dennis Görlich (2020) compiled a summary of these efforts since 2017 (Policy Briefs on Migrant-related issues are available at https://www.g20-insights.org/policy_area/youth-aging-population-migration/). However, most proposals have been relatively limited. For example, Stam, et al. (2019) proposed making company-based social security and pension scheme portable over different organizations to promote labor mobility and innovation.

The international implementation of the IPPS would require cooperation from the private sector. G20 governments should encourage major private international financial intermediaries such as mutual fund (unit trust) management companies to offer highly competitive and efficient IMPIAs, and form a global network of collaborating companies to facilitate account transfers for workers changing jobs across national borders.

To safeguard the integrity of the program and protect the savings entrusted in IMPIAs, the G20 and the financial sector would develop investment guidelines for IMPIAs. The binding guidelines would minimize the risk of IMPIAs being diverted towards financially questionable projects and would impose the fiduciary duty on asset managers to align their interests exclusively with the interests of shareholders: the migrant workers. Moreover, the investment guidelines would impose strict limits on holdings of sovereign debt (limited to short-term liquidity management) and prohibit investing in securities issued to support what in principle are quasi-fiscal operations, such as non-market-based financing schemes. Mandating the use of broadly diversified and well-known market indices would depoliticize the investment process and reduce management and trading costs.

The “Tax Treatment and Treaty” Model would provide for the uniform tax treatment of savings in the IMPIAs and facilitate their full, unencumbered international portability. The Model would include a tax treaty to facilitate post-tax contributions (tax-free accumulation – tax-free withdrawal) or pre-tax contributions (tax-free accumulation – taxable withdrawal).

Proposed Country-Level Mechanism

We propose a mechanism that recognizes low-income migrant workers comprising both formal and informal workers. The mechanism draws on findings from behavioral economics to improve take-up. This takes the form of a contribution to the IMPIAs made during regular remittance transactions, with an added financial incentive to encourage contributions.

The decision to include informal migrant workers suggests that operating through traditional government or employer channels would not be effective. Additionally, socioeconomic characteristics (e.g. age, income, education), as well as location of work (rural vs urban), can be determining factors for participation in national micro-pension schemes by informal workers (Agravat and Kaplelach, 2017; Collins-Sowah, et al., 2013).

Thus, an effective mechanism must be able to capture less-educated, low-income, informal migrant workers working in rural areas (e.g. as farm workers). We suggest a mechanism to leverage on the international remittances system. Migrant workers regularly remit funds back to their home countries, providing a useful avenue to allow them to interact with the IPPS. Administration costs would be minimized as remittance operators/agents would be situated in areas of convenience for migrant workers, have Know Your Customer (KYC) in place, and be seen as trusted parties. The regular KYC requirements for remittances would fulfill the onboarding/updating of KYC for individual IMPIAs. Remittances also require recipient information which can be easily incorporated as a beneficiary of the IMPIAs in the event of death. The global nature of IPPS and IMPIAs as well as remittance being carried out regularly would allow migrants that move to different countries for work to continue providing their latest personal and beneficiary details. Additionally, remittances can be thought of not just to facilitate consumption transfer to families abroad, but also as alternative savings mechanisms (Quinn, 2005).

Facilitating contributions to IMPIAs via remittances also allows the scheme to align with and benefit from the SDG goal to reduce remittance costs. Target 10.c of the Sustainable Development Goals is “By 2030, reduce to less than 3 percent the transaction costs of migrant remittances and eliminate remittance corridors with costs higher than 5 percent” (United Nations, 2021). This is measured based on the cost to send US$200, which was on average 6.51 percent in 2020 compared to 9.30 percent in 2011 (United Nations, 2021). Currently, lower fees are passed on as savings, which could be adapted as contributions to the IMPIAs. Channeling the remaining 3.51 percent in reduced fees by 2030 towards a low-cost portable pension scheme would act as a credible savings option that supplements rather than competes with the traditional savings/investment schemes in the remittance destinations.

Here we can apply the inertia of defaults to encourage contributions.[6] The mechanism could be set such that the remittance would consist of the 3 percent fee and a 3.51 percent contribution to the IPPS or IMPIA. The migrant worker retains the right to instead choose to not make the contribution or to make additional voluntary contributions, retaining the libertarian paternalism choice architecture (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008). However, migrant workers may use alternative remittance channels such as hawala or physically carrying funds overseas. Therefore, an additional incentive to use the traditional remittance channels would benefit the proposal of this policy brief, as well as facilitate the shift from informal to formal finance.

The proposed incentive would be US$100 deposited in the IMPIA of every migrant worker upon their first remittance transaction with a contribution to the IPPS that year. However, they would only get to keep the full US$100 if, by the end of the year, they made contributions based on an accumulated US$1,000 of remittances during the year. The US$100 incentive would be pro-rated should accumulated remittances during the year be under US$1,000. Phrasing the incentive in this manner would trigger the endowment effect and loss aversion; resulting in an increased likelihood for the migrant workers to make the contributions to obtain the “free” US$100 that they were initially given (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008). Relative to the remittances sent, the incentive would be an additional 10 percent, while relative to the contributions (3.51 percent of US$1,000) it would be 285 percent. The average migrant sends between US$200-US$300 home every 1-2 months, so this remittance threshold should serve as a reasonable baseline (United Nations, 2019).

The funding for the US$100 would be provided through an equivalent increase in the annual visa fees for these migrant workers. This funding mechanism recognizes the importance for employers to contribute to the longer-term welfare of the migrant workers they employ. This would also limit administrative costs by operating as part of existing visa processes.

The longer-term financial sustainability of this incentive could be strengthened through a mechanism designed to disincentivize higher-income migrant workers from claiming the incentive. For example, only having qualifying remittances from operators/agents that typically serve low-income migrant workers. Alternatively, the visa fees for higher-income migrant workers could be increased by more than US$100. Furthermore, it is unlikely to achieve 100 percent take-up even with informal migrant workers that work without visas. Additionally, the visa fees would be collected in advance of the migrant workers’ labor for the year, allowing these funds to be invested in money markets to generate short-term safe returns that can also be used to cover administrative costs. The exact amounts for the financial incentive and contributions could be adjusted based on country circumstances to further ensure sustainability.

Domestic financial sector development would be supported through the need for intermediaries (trustees, custodians, money managers) for the domestic short-term management of IPPS and IMPIAs funds prior to regular transfers to the globally managed pension portfolio. Operating through remittance operators/agents also opens up opportunities for these entities to branch out into innovative micro-savings and micro-finance products.

This mechanism would also support the achievement of SDG 10.c by incentivizing a shift from informal to formal remittances in order to benefit from the financial incentive and the micro-pension. This would increase overall remittance volumes, allowing for the lowering of fees. The opening up of additional product offerings by remittance operators/agents would also create new revenue streams that may encourage cross-subsidization of remittance fees. Overall, we argue that this is a robust country-level mechanism for IPPS and IMPIAs that takes into account informality as well as behavioral economics to ensure low-income migrant workers are nudged into contributing to their longer-term welfare.

Further Considerations

  • The experience with setting up long-term savings-pension schemes shows the importance of a single objective exclusively focused on the welfare of the schemes’ participants. Prudently managed portable schemes will inevitably result in continuously increasing income, wealth, and social welfare, and thus help indirectly meet the Sustainable Development Goals while reducing the demands for fiscal spending and tax revenue mobilization.
  • Contribution rates to the savings accounts could increase over time. For example, a share of the employee’s future salary increases could be dedicated to their savings account (Benartzi and Thaler, 2004).
  • Countries with existing centralized national provident funds, such as Brunei Darussalam, Malaysia, or Singapore, have gained valuable experience in managing, expanding, and improving their provident funds. They could allow migrants to benefit from the discipline and low administrative costs offered by such platforms and share their experiences with other countries.
  • Countries should strive to minimize administrative and fund management costs by pooling together assets and using tracking indices. The annual expense ratio of many large U.S.-based index funds is less than 5 basis points of the net asset value under management. This is a small fraction of the fees charged—to the detriment of savers—by funds in most developed and developing countries (French, 2008).
  • Offering balanced investment products to beginner or high-risk aversion savers-investors could help them gain familiarity with international financial markets while ensuring participation in equity markets from the start.
  • Rules could allow account owners to self-manage investments for balances exceeding a pre-set minimum balance.[7] People opting for self-management could be required to periodically review their investment performance against the performance of the trust fund to learn their true investment skills.
  • Including migrants in pension schemes would bring relevance and emotional connection to financial education programs, two necessary conditions for the effectiveness of financial education that would inevitably accompany the rollout of the schemes (Berg and Zia, 2013; Bayer, et al., 1996).

The finance industry may argue that the program could harm private finance and reduce employment. However, the program’s main target audience would be migrant workers, a group currently underserved by finance. Moreover, investors are already embracing indexing as they learn to appreciate the adverse impact on their earnings of asset management costs. Finance will continue to develop at a very healthy pace by offering genuine value, such as in private equity, which, in addition to financing, can deliver managerial capital to raise productivity.

References

Agnew, Julie and Joshua Hurwitz, “Financial Education and Choice in State Public Pension Systems,” NBER Working Paper No. 18907 (March 2013)

Agravat, Deepali Rajendra and Samson Kaplelach, “Effect of Demographic Characteristics on Micro-Pension Uptake Among Informal Employees of Kenya Ports Authority,” in Journal of Business and Strategic Management, Vol. 2, No. 2 (2017), p. 95-117

Barr, Nicholas, “The Role of the Public and Private Sectors in Ensuring Adequate Pensions – Theoretical Considerations,” IMF Conference Co-Hosted By Regional Office For Asia And The Pacific And Fiscal Affairs Department, “Designing Fiscally Sustainable and Equitable Pension Systems in Asia in the Post-crisis World” January 9 – 10, 2013, Tokyo, Japan, available at  https://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2013/oapfad/pdf/barr.pdf; (December 2012) https://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2013/oapfad/pdf/barr_ppr.pdf

Barro, Robert J. and Sanjay Misra, “Gold Returns,” NBER Working Paper No. 18759 (February 2013)

Bayer, Patrick J., B. Douglas Bernheim and John Karl Scholz, “The Effects of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Employers,” NBER Working Paper No. 5655 (July 1996)

Benartzi, Shlomo and Richard H. Thaler, “How Much Is Investor Autonomy Worth?” in Journal of Finance, Vol. 57, pp. 1593-1616 (December 2002)

Benartzi, Shlomo and Richard H. Thaler, “Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving,” in Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 112, No. 1, pp. S164-S187 (February 2004)

Berg, Gunhild and Bilal Zia, “Harnessing Emotional Connections to Improve Financial Decisions: Evaluating the Impact of Financial Education in Mainstream Media,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6407 (April 2013) SSRN https://ssrn.com/abstract=2248477

Beshears, John, James J. Choi, David Laibson and Brigitte C. Madrian, “The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Savings Outcomes: Evidence from the United States,” NBER Working Paper No. 12009 (January 2006)

Borghans, Lex, Bart Golsteyn, James J. Heckman and Huub Meijers, 2009, “Gender Differences in Risk Aversion and Ambiguity Aversion,” NBER Working Paper No. 14713 (February 2009)

Brown, Jeffrey R. and Scott J. Weisbenner, “Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans?” NBER Working Paper No. 12842 (January 2007)

Camerer, Colin F., Samuel Issacharoff, George F. Loewenstein, Ted O’Donoghue and Matthew Rabin, “Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism,’ in University of Pennsylvania Law Review, Vol. 151: 1211, 2003; Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper No. 225 (April 2003), available on https://ssrn.com/abstract=399501

Caplin, Andrew and Daniel J. Martin, “Defaults and Attention: The Drop Out Effect,” NBER Working Paper No. 17988 (April 2012)

Carroll, Gabriel D., James J. Choi, David I. Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian and Andrew Metrick, “Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions,” NBER Working Paper No. 11074 (January 2005)

Choi, James J., David I. Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian and Andrew Metrick, “Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Decisions and the Path of Least Resistance,” NBER Working Paper No. 8655 (December 2001a)

Choi, James J., David I. Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian and Andrew Metrick, “For Better or for Worse: Default Effects and 401(K) Savings Behavior,” NBER Working Paper No. 8651 (December 2001b)

Cole, Shawn Allen and Gauri Kartini Shastry, “Smart Money: The Effect of Education, Cognitive Ability, and Financial Literacy on Financial Market Participation,” in Harvard Business School Finance Working Paper No. 09-071 (April 2012) SSRN https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1317298

Collins-Sowah, Peron A., John K. M. Kuwornu and Daniel Tsegai, “Willingness to participate in micro pension schemes: Evidence from the informal sector in Ghana”, in Journal of Economics and International Finance, Vol. 5, No. 1 (April 2013), p. 21-34

Ehrlich, Isaac and Jinyoung Kim, “Social Security, Demographic Trends, and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence from the International Experience,” NBER Working Paper 11121 (February 2005)

Euzéby, A., “Social Security: Indispensable Solidarity,” in International Social Security Review, 50: 3–15 (July 1997)

French, Kenneth R., “The Cost of Active Investing,” (April 2008) https://ssrn.com/abstract=1105775

Fultz, Elaine, “The Retrenchment of Second-tier Pensions in Hungary and Poland: A Precautionary Tale,” in International Social Security Review, 65: 1–25 (July 2012)

Genser, Bernd and Robert Holzmann, “Frontloaded Income Taxation of Old-Age Pensions: For Efficiency and Fairness in a World of International Labor Mobility,” in CESifo Economic Studies, March 2021, pages 61–77

Grimalda, Gianluca (lead author), Fernando Filgueira, Marc Fleurbaey and Rubén Lo Vuolo, “Building Global Citizenship through a Global Citizen Income And Progressive Global Taxation, T20 Task Force 6 Social Cohesion and the Future of Welfare Systems Policy Brief (September 2021)

Hartley, Gonzalo Reyes, Jan C. van Ours, Milan Vodopivec, “Incentive Effects of Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts: Evidence from Chile,” IZA DP No. 4681 (January 2010)

Hirose, Kenichi, Miloš Nikacˇ and Edward Tamagno, “Social Security for Migrant Workers A Rights-Based Approach.”  ILO Decent Work Technical Support Team and Country Office for Central and Eastern Europe, International Labor Organization (2011)

Holzmann, R., “Global Pension Systems and Their Reform: Worldwide Drivers, Trends and Challenges,” in International Social Security Review, 66: 1–29 (Apri-June 2013)

Holzmann, Robert, Jacques Wels and Pamela Dale, “Assessing Benefit Portability for International Migrant Workers: A Review of the Belgium-Morocco Bilateral Social Security Agreement,” in Social Protection and Labor Discussion Paper No. 1603, World Bank Group (May 2016)

ILO, Migrant Forum in Asia, “Social Protection for Low-Skilled Migrant Workers and their Families,” Responding to Emerging and Critical Issues, Policy Brief No. 7 (September 2013)  https://www.ilo.org/dyn/migpractice/docs/137/PB7.pdf

ILO, “ILO Global Estimates on International Migrant Workers — Results and Methodology — Third edition,” International Labour Office – Geneva: ILO, 2021  https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/—dgreports/—dcomm/—publ/documents/publication/wcms_808935.pdf

International Social Security Association (ISSA), “Handbook on the Extension of Social Security Coverage to Migrant Workers,” (2014) https://ww1.issa.int/sites/default/files/documents/publications/2-handbook-extension-migrants-26562.pdf

Jensen, Michael C. and William H. Meckling, “The Nature of Man,” in Michael C. Jensen, Foundations of Organizational Strategy, Harvard University Press, 1998; or Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Volume 7, No. 2, pages 4-19 (Summer 1994)

Kay, S. J., “Political Risk and Pension Privatization: The Case of Argentina (1994-2008),” in International Social Security Review, 62: 1–21 (July-September 2009)

Khorunzhina, Natalia, “Structural Estimation of Stock Market Participation Costs,” in Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control Elsevier, vol. 37(12) pages 2928-2942 (December 2013)

Kok, Jason, Ariadna Bankowska and Roman Zytek,  https://www.researchgate.net/publication/361548007_Optimal_Decision_Making_in_the_Context_Behavioural_Biases_Annex_to_Think_20_T20_Task_Force_5_Inequality_Human_Capital_and_Well-being_Policy_Brief_Towards_an_International_Model_of_Portable_Migrant_Soc (June 2022)

Lusardi, Annamaria, “Numeracy, Financial Literacy, and Financial Decision-Making,” NBER Working Paper No. 17821 (February 2012)

Quinn, Micheal A., “Remittances, Savings, and Relative Rates of Return”, in The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 38, No. 2 (Spring 2005), p. 1-23

Redonda, Agustin, Vincenzo Galasso, Mark Mazur, Miranda Stewart and Matthew Whittaker, “Taxation in Aging Societies: Increasing the Effectiveness and Fairness of Pension Systems,” T20 2019, Task Force “Aging Population and Its Economic Impact + Immigration” (March 15, 2019)

Sabates-Wheeler and Johannes Koettl, “Social Protection for Migrants: The Challenges of Delivery in The Context of Changing Migration Flows,” in International Social Security Review, 63: 115–144 (September 2010)

Schulz, J. H., “The Evolving Concept of “Retirement”: Looking Forward to the Year 2050.” In International Social Security Review, 55: 85–105 (December 2002)

Stam, Erik, Niels Bosma and Hiroyuki Okamuro, “Promoting Investment in Human Capital and Labor Mobility: Making the Entrepreneurial Economy Work,” T20 2019 Policy Brief (Task Force SME Policy Faced With Development of Financial Technology) (March 28, 2019)

Stein-Zalai, Juliane and Dennis Görlich (compilers), “Social Cohesion and the State,” T20 Recommendations Report Work in Progress (January 16, 2020) https://www.global-solutions-initiative.org/wp-content/uploads/g20-insights-uploads/2020/04/T20-Recommendations-Report-Social-cohesion-and-the-state.pdf

Thaler, Richard H. and Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness, Yale University Press, 2008

Thaler, Richard H., Cass R. Sunstein and John P. Balz, “Choice Architecture,” (April 2010) https://ssrn.com/abstract=1583509

United Nations, Remittances matter: 8 facts you don’t know about the money migrants send back home, United Nations, New York, 17 June 2019. Available from: https://www.un.org/development/desa/en/news/population/remittances-matter.html

United Nations, “The Sustainable Development Goals Report 2021.” United Nations, 2021

Verho, Jouko, Kari Hämäläinen and Ohto Kanninen, “Removing Welfare Traps: Employment Responses in the Finnish Basic Income Experiment,” in American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 14 (1): 501-22 (February 2022)

Vogel, Edgar, Alexander Ludwig and Axel H. Borsch-Supan, “Aging and Pension Reform: Extending the Retirement Age and Human Capital Formation,” NBER Working Paper No. 18856 (March 2013)

 

Appendix

Economists routinely assume that people are rational decision makers. Studies in behavioral economics shed doubt on this assumption and offer food-for-thought for policy makers designing pension schemes. It is important to understand behavioral biases and market imperfections that result in poor investment decisions. Low propensity to save and weak asset management have contributed to rising income and wealth inequality, possibly more than differences in labor income. For a summary of several important behavioral biases, please see (Kok, Bankowska, Zytek 2022).

  1. In 2019, the last year for which data is available, there were an estimated 169 million international migrant workers, constituting 4.9 percent of the global labor force (ILO, 2021). The majority of migrant workers were in three subregions: 24.2 percent in Northern, Southern and Western Europe, 22.1 percent in North America and 14.3 percent in the Arab States. Collectively, these three regions hosted 60.6 percent of migrant workers in 2019. Asia hosted 19.8 percent of migrant workers. 
  2.  The Equality of Treatment (Accident Compensation) Convention, 1925 (No. 19) 121 ratifications as of April 14, 2022. The Maintenance of Migrants’ Pension Rights Convention, 1935 (No. 48) 12 ratifications and 4 denouncements, subsequently included in Convention No 118. The Social Security (Minimum Standards) Convention, 1952 (No. 102) 61 ratifications (no country in Middle East, no South Asian or South East Asian country). The Equality of Treatment (Social Security) Convention, 1962 (No. 118) 38 ratifications (some countries accepted compliance with only just a few of the 9 branches of social security: (a) medical care; (b) sickness benefit; (c) maternity benefit; (d) invalidity benefit; (e) old-age benefit; (f) survivors’ benefit; (g) employment injury benefit; (h) unemployment benefit; and (i) family benefit. Only 18 countries accepted branch “e” – old-age benefit. The Maintenance of Social Security Rights Convention, 1982 (No. 157) 4 ratifications (Sweden, Spain, The Philippines, Kyrgyz Republic).
  3. Following Jensen and Meckling (1994), we accept the view that in their rational part people are “resourceful, evaluative maximizers” (REMs). To be effective, public policies must take into account people’s responses to policies, including the unintended ones. 
  4.  Ehrlich and Kim (2005, p. 3) identify the following adverse socio-economic consequences of the PAYG social security system: “Controlling for a host of other contributing factors, we find that the ratio of social security’s pension benefits to GDP, which approximates the system’s equilibrium tax rate (PEN), has adverse effects on: a. the rate of marriage net of divorce − decreasing marriage and increasing divorce; b. the total fertility rate; c. the private savings rate; and d. schooling attainment measures and per-capita GDP growth rates. These effects are especially large for family formation and fertility, and in OECD countries; they are not duplicated when PEN is replaced by a benefits measure that includes other welfare programs; and they are generally not observed in countries where social security is a provident fund, rather than a defined-benefits, PAYG system.” […] “Our model also suggests that higher social taxes crowd out intergenerational transfers going from children to old parents – the traditional family security system.” 
  5. “The Development Working Group (DWG) was created in 2010. It has become an essential forum to discuss and promote action on a broad range of issues directly affecting developing countries, especially low-income countries. In 2016, the G20 entrusted the DWG with coordinating and monitoring policy actions across all G20 countries related to the United Nations 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development.” The mandate of the Working Group on Employment (established in 2014) is to address the priority issues related to labour. The group elaborates shared guidelines aimed at promoting employment, improving working conditions and triggering economic environments able to foster strong, sustainable, balanced and inclusive growth. To this end, it promotes shared responsibility between stakeholders and develops policy principles and methodologies aimed at ensuring effective implementation of policies and programmes.” https://g20.org/sherpa-track/.  “In 2010, the Global Partnership for Financial Inclusion was created to advance financial inclusion globally as a means of increasing well-being and achieving sustainable and inclusive growth. The focus of its action is to enhance the access to, and the use of, responsible formal financial services – also through digital means – for families and businesses. It also helps to promote adequate financial education and to strengthen financial consumer protection.” https://g20.org/finance-track/ 
  6. Studies show that participation in a retirement fund is “significantly higher under automatic enrolment” (Camerer, et al., 2003, p. 1211; Beshears, et al., 2006) and defaults are universally beneficial (Carroll, et al., 2005; Choi, et al., 2001a, 2001b), including for the more educated (Agnew and Hurwitz, 2013; Brown and Weisbenner, 2007). Default rules often determine choice due to heuristics, inertia, and ill-formed or not well-defined preferences that result in lack of or poor decisions and large foregone income over one’s lifetime (Benartzi and Thaler, 2002). 
  7. For example, Singapore’s Central Provident Fund allows savers to invest in the CPF Investment Scheme (CPFIS) and Special Discounted Shares (SDS) Scheme after they reach a certain minimum balance in their Ordinary Account. https://www.cpf.gov.sg/member/growing-your-savings/earning-higher-returns/investing-your-cpf-savings

Latest Policy Briefs

Register for Updates

Would you like to receive updates on the Global Solutions Initiative, upcoming events, G7 and G20-related developments and the future of multilateralism? Then subscribe here!

1 You hereby agree that the personal data provided may be used for the purpose of updates on the Global Solutions Initiative by the Global Solutions Initiative Foundation gemeinnützige GmbH. Your consent is revocable at any time (by e-mail to contact@global-solutions-initiative.org or to the contact data given in the imprint). The update is sent in accordance with the privacy policy and to advertise the Global Solutions Initiative’s own products and services.